文档视界 最新最全的文档下载
当前位置:文档视界 › 特朗普经济学与中美贸易失衡外文文献翻译

特朗普经济学与中美贸易失衡外文文献翻译

特朗普经济学与中美贸易失衡外文文献翻译
特朗普经济学与中美贸易失衡外文文献翻译

特朗普经济学与中美贸易失衡中英文

英文

Trump economics and China–US trade imbalances

Justin YifuLin

1. Introduction

The trade deficit of the Unites States, as shown in Fig, expanded from around zero before mid-1970s to peak in 2006 at $761 billion, which was around 5% of the US GDP. The trade deficit of goods was even larger, peaking at $837 billion in 2006. Though this value decreased after the 2008 global financial crisis, it was still at a remarkably high level as $752 billion in 2016. The trade imbalances between US and Japan and other industrialized economies contributed most to the rising US trade deficits before the 1980s, while in recent years the US runs deficits mainly against emerging Asian economies and oil-producing economies. President Trump argues that the US trade deficit was caused by unfavorable trade agreements against the US and pledges to eliminate them by bilateral renegotiations or unilateral actions.

The US–China trade imbalance has been a prime concern of President Trump ever since his election campaign in 2015. The official data provided by the US Census Bureau shows that China, the emerging major player in the process of globalization, has been running a trade surplus with the US since 1984. China’s trade balance with the US

increased from a trade surplus of $0.06 billion in 1985 to a trade surplus of $347.02 billion in 2016, which represented 44% of US trade deficit in that year. This large imbalance has caused considerable pressure on the US–China trade relations. One major concern is the impacts of imports from China on US domestic employment. One highly cited work by Autor, Dorn, and Hanson (2013) shows that the exposure to imports from China had negative impacts on US’s manufacturing employment. President Trump pledged in his election campaign to impose 45% border tax on imports from China as a measure to reduce the US–China trade imbalances and to retain jobs in the US.

Would imposing draconian tariffs on imports from China help reduce US total trade deficit? Would the reduction of US trade deficit with China bring manufacturing jobs back to the US? The answer to these questions depends on what cause the persistent trade imbalances.

The causes of rising US trade deficit have been discussed intensively. Existing literature provides theoretical and empirical support for several key factors, such as the lack of investment opportunities in emerging economies, undervalued exchange rates against the US dollar to the currencies of several emerging economies, the increase in the price of the primary commodities and the over-consumption caused by financial deregulation and supported by US dollar as a major global reserve currency.

This paper focuses specifically on trade imbalances between the US and China and investigates how China’s comparative advantage in the labor-intensive manufacturing activities, combined with the global production sharing across economies with China as the assembly hub, works as the major source of the increasing bilateral trade imbalances between US and China. In particular, this paper first analyzes the bilateral trade patterns between US and its main trading partners and finds that East Asia is traditionally the main source of US’s trade deficits. The paper further finds a declining share of US–East Asia trade imbalances in US total trade deficit during the period when the US–China trade imbalances was rising. It also reveals negative correlation between US trade deficit with China and China with some other East Asian economies. Based on these findings, our paper attributes the sharp increase in US–China trade imbalances to the reallocation of labor-intensive production activities from Japan and Asian newly industrialized economies (NIEs), namely South Korea, Singapore, Hong Kong, Taiwan, China, to China, epitomized by the US’s dramati c expansion of overall trade deficit.

The US–China trade imbalances were also exacerbated by the production sharing across borders in East Asia with China as the assembly hub. A growing strand of literature considers the value-added contents as an indicator for international production fragmentation and a more objective assessment of the relative distribution of economic

benefits from trade between two trading partner economies (Daudin, Rifflart, & Schweisguth, 2011; Hummels, Ishii, & Yi, 2001; Johnson & Noguera, 2012). The idea of value-added contents of trade is based on models of sequential multi-stage production with stages split across economies. With flows of final products and intermediates co-existing, production fragmentation across economies generates discrepancy between gross and value-added trade flows. Traditionally, the focus of public interest is on the bilateral trade balance. However, with trade flows of intermediates across economies, the value of gross exports might overestimate the domestic economic benefits of exports to the exporting country and ignores the indirect impacts from other economies. Therefore, in addition to the bilateral trade balance, this paper carefully discusses patterns of bilateral trade flows measured in value-added contents, with data in Johnson and Noguera (2012) and Johnson (2014).

Moreover, given that the difference in comparative advantages across economies is one of the main incentives of global production sharing, this paper examines the bilateral trade balances at the sector level. The results show that only in sectors that China has comparative advantages there is persistent bilateral trade imbalance between China and US. In addition, other economies that has low labor costs share the same trade pattern as that of China. We argue that the root of US trade deficit is not China’s exchange rate policy and other trade manipulations

as President Trump pledged. Therefore, raising trade barriers for China’s imports to the US will not help mitigate the US total trade deficits.

This paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we review several explanations for US trade deficits. Sector 3 presents the current status of the total US–China trade imbalances, and we further examine its domestic value-added contents in Section 4. In Section 5 we conduct our analysis by sectors and apply the analysis to other economies. We also discuss the evolution of China’s comparative advantages in the low-wage labor intensive sector. Section 6 concludes.

2. Main explanations for US trade deficits in existing literature

The causes of US trade deficits have been extensively discussed. In this section, we will review several main strands of existing literature. The first strand of literature considers the trade imbalances as the results of econ omic distortions rather than an “equilibrium” phenomenon. Therefore, the trade imbalances could only be resolved with policy adjustments. For example, a series papers by Obstfeld and Rogoff, 2000, Obstfeld and Rogoff, 2005 and Rogoff (2006) discuss the changes in exchange rate that are required to reduce the imbalances.

The second strand of literature considering global imbalances as an “equilibrium” condition, marked with the hypothesis of a global “saving-glut” proposed by Bernanke (2005). Different explanations of the “saving glut” have been raised. Caballero, Farhi, and Gourinchas (2008),

for example, develops a model with heterogeneity across economies in their ability to supply safe assets. Mendoza, Quadrini, and Rios-Rull (2009) also focuses on the different levels of financial development, but emphasizes heterogeneity in the demand of assets and their model predicts increased financial integration raises foreign demand for US assets. Fogli and Perri (2010) explore the impacts of time varying macro risk, while several papers consider demographic heterogeneity as one reason for the emergence of external imbalances, such as Henriksen (2002), Cooper (2008), and Du and Wei (2010).

Other explanations for global imbalances include the anticipation of a rising U.S. future share in world output, trade channels, productivity growth in the non-traded sector, measurement error, the asset price boom of the late nineties (Laibson & Mollerstrom, 2010), etc.

In other study, Lin (2013) has reviewed the above explanations and argued that the deterioration of US trade deficits after the mid-1970s is caused primarily by the US household’s overconsumption as a result of the wealth effect from rising asset value due to financial deregulation and the expansionary monetary policy, which in turn were made possible by the delink of US dollar to gold in 1971. Moreover, the only reason for the US to be able to sustain such a large and rising trade deficits for several decades is the status of US dollar as a major global reserve currency.

In this paper we focus particularly on the US–China trade

imbalances. Unlike the cases in which economic reasons are employed to explain US trade deficit with Japan and the oil exporting economies, China and other East Asian economies have been blamed, by some researchers and politicians, to manipulate the exchange rate to promote net exports and use this as the main components of export-led growthdevelopment strategy. In this paper, we will show that the US traditionally has a trade deficit with the East Asian economies due to the differences in comparative advantages between the US and East Asian economies and the rising bilateral trade imbalances between the US and China is a result of reallocation of production from Asia’s NIEs to China due to the evolution of comparative advantages over time. The US has trade imbalance with East Asian economies traditionally. While China’s trade imbalance with US increased sharply after the 1990s, the share of US’s trade imbalance with East Asian economies as a gro up declined in the same period. The facts suggest that the US’s worsening of trade deficits in general and trade imbalance with China in specific are most likely to be a result of US’s own internal reasons.

3. Current status of US–China trade imbalance

Since the official estimates of the same bilateral trade deficit often differs across trading partners, we only employ the trade values reported by importers as described in Feenstra, Lipsey, Deng, Ma, & Mo (2005) for the following analysis. present the main reasons that make

China almost the sole concern among all economies with trade surplus with US. First, there has been continuous dramatic increases in the trade surplus of China for more than three decades while the trade imbalances of the main trading partners of US were much more stable since 1985. Japan’s trade surplus, for example, was $103 billion in 1985 and $110 billion in 2016. This increase was much lower than the case of China, from ?$16 billion in 1985 to $608 billion in 2016. In addition, US’s trade deficit with China accounts for the major part of its total trade deficit in recent years. In 2016, 44% of US total trade deficit was with China, while this value was only 0.3% in 1985.

However, these facts provide little evidence to support the idea that imposing high trade barriers for imports from China could help reduce US total trade deficit. A closer examination of the contribution of East Asian economies to US trade deficit reveals more evidence. There are two main messages from Panel B. First, as argued in Lin, Dinh, & Im (2010) US began to accumulate trade deficit long before the start of China’s trade surplus. US has had large trade deficit with East Asian as a whole before the rising of China’s exports since the 1990s. The pattern of East Asi an’s contribution to US trade deficit has been relatively stable during the past three decades, except for the peak in the 90s. Moreover, although the contribution of China to US trade deficit increases dramatically since 1990, the total share of trade surplus of East Asian

economies4 in US total trade deficit declined from over 100% in early 1990s and 83.3% in 1995 to 63.1% in 2016. It implicates that the policies in China and East Asian economies were not the main reason for the US trade deficits and the increase in US–China trade deficit is associated with the reallocation of production activities across East Asian economies.

The international reallocation of production activities, mainly labor-intensive activities, has been discussed in the literature under the term of “fly-geese”. The flying-geese theory (Akamatsu, 1962), as discussed in Kojima (2000) and its empirical work, mainly examine the sequential economic development in all “high-performing Asian economies” (HPEAs), which “trickled down from Japa n, to the NIEs, and then to ASEAN-4 (Thailand, Malaysia, Indonesia, and the Philippines), and China” (Cutler, Berri, & Ozawa, 2003). Japan was the first Asian country that experienced a dramatic structural transformation with expansion in its labor-intensive manufacturing sector and exports to the US after WWII. While its wage increased in the latter half of the 1960s, the labor-intensive manufacturing shifted to South Korea, Singapore, Hong Kong, and Taiwan, China. These production activities mirgrated again to the ASEAN-4 and China in 1980s, with 1990s as the peak time of FDI inflows to China (Chandra, Lin, & Wang, 2013; Lin, 2012, Lin, 2013).

Inspired by the literature on the flying-geese-style economic

development, we further examine the correlation among changes in the bilateral trade flows across economies. If our argument of production reallocation holds, increases in China’s trade surplus with US should be accompanied by increases in China’s trade deficit (or decreases in trade surplus) with South Korea and Taiwan, China after 1980s. The fitted lines in two graphs in Fig are both downward sloping, indicating a negative correlation between China’s trade imbalance with US and China’s trade imbalances with South Korea, as well as the one between China–US trade imbalances and China–Taiwan, China trade imbalances. In addition, China started to hold trade deficit with both South Korea and Taiwan, China after around 1990. This is also the start of the dramatic increase of China’s trade surplus with US. The ti ming pattern fits well with empirical evidence in the fly-geese style economic development literature.

Since Japan finished its structural change and production reallocation before 1980. However, this graph is still consistent with the fly-geese story since the China–Japan trade grew in favor of Japan until 1990. In addition, if we divided the time of our concern into two periods, we see that before 2000, there existed a positive correlation between China’s net trade with Japan and with US, while this patte rn was reversed after 2001.

Actually the “triangular production sharing within Asia” has been

discussed in several papers. Johnson and Noguera (2012), for instance, finds that the adjustments of trade balances in Australia, Japan, Singapore, South Korea, and Taiwan, China nearly add up to the changes in the US–China deficit. The production fragmentation and sharing implies the possibility that large part of China’s exports to the US were intermediates that China imported from these economies.

4. Value added content of US–China trade imbalance

To find further support for production fragmentation, we next check the value-added share of exports in each economy as an indicator of the intensity of production sharing in the production network, as discussed by Johnson and Noguera (2012). When there exists production fragmentation, firms locate their production affiliation according to the comparative advantage in each country over the world. It helps firms reduce costs and gain more profits. In this case, what matters for the impacts of trade on employment is the value-added contents in trade flows rather than the total trade values.

The value added (V A) content is defined as the difference between the value of output and the total value of purchased intermediate inputs. It includes compensation for labor and capital and indirect taxes. China is often engaged in the final stage of production by assembling intermediate parts before products are exported to final consumers. Consequently, the total domestic value-added c ontent of China’s exports is relatively low. In

contrast, the value-added content of U.S. exports to China is high, which implies that the imbalances in the gross value of trade flows between the U.S. and China have been overstated the actual trade imbalances that might have asymmetric impacts on economic results of two trading paternals. In addition, China imports large quantity of intermediate goods from South Korea and Taiwan, China. However, with simple processing in China, these products are exported to US and other economies. The calculation of overall trade flows counts their whole value into China’s exports to US rather than exports from South Korea and Taiwan, China. Therefore, it underestimates the impacts of other economies on US imbalance. In this section, we check the value-added contents of trade based on the value-added datasets provided by Johnson and Noguera (2012) and Johnson (2014).

With regards to the bilateral trade flows, the most significant change appears in the value of trade imbalances between US and China. This is because the share of domestic contents containing in China’s exports to US is much lower than the share of other economies’ exports. This value would be even smaller if we adjust the results for processing trade (Johnson & Noguera, 2012; Wang, Wei, Yu, & Zhu, 2017; Wang, Wei, & Zhu, 2013). In addition, Panel A in Fig. 8 shows that the gap between the value added contents and total value of trade imbalances with US is rising for China. However, as illustrated in Panel B and Panel C, this share is

quite stable for Japan and South Korea, with slight increases. South Korea’s trade surplus with US is almost the same with the two measurements, with a few exceptions in which the domestic value-added value was higher than the overall trade imbalances. It implicates that the production activities differ across economies.

5. Further discussion

5.1. Bilateral trade flows by sectors

The main incentive for firms to split its production process is to seek lower cost around the world. Therefore, if the fragmentation of production contributes to the increase of bilateral trade imbalances between US and China, one should expect the conclusions in our previous discussion only hold for sectors that China has comparative advantages. Therefore, next we consider the correlation between China–US bilateral trade imbalances and the trade imbalances between China and South Korea, Japan and Taiwan, China as a group by sectors. It provides evidence consistent with our expectation. China’s trade deficit wit h East Asian economies and trade surplus with US only coexist in the manufacturing sector, which is where China’s comparative advantage lies. In addition, the negative correlation between the two balances of bilateral trade only exists for the agriculture and manufacturing sector, while the correlation is shown to be positive in the non-manufacturing industrial production7 and service sector.

To support the argument that China mainly involves labor-intensive production process, we further investigate the share of value added in the tech-intensive industries and labor-intensive industries. The domestic value-added share of China’s exports to US in the labor-intensive sectors was raised from less than 45% in 1995 to more than 55% in 2009, while this value in the technology-intensive industries decreased sharply after China’s accession to WTO in 2001. The domestic value-added share was around 35% in 2009, which provides support of “fly-geese” story that firms in South Korea and Taiwan, China mainly moved their labor-intensive production activities, such as processing, to China.

5.2. Bilateral trade flows of other economies

As one of the many recipient economies of reallocated production activities from NIEs, China is not a special case in any sense. The above analysis holds for other low-wage economies in China’s neighborhood as well, such as Vietnam and India. The negative correlation discussed above is shown in the case of both India and Vietnam, and only exists in tech-intensive manufacturing industries. Therefore, as long as US still trades with other emerging economies with low wage, closing its deficit with China by imposing high import tariff would cause outmigration of labor-intensive manufacturing to other low-wage emerging economies and help little to bring employment back to the goods-producing sectors in US.

5.3. Changes in patterns of China’s comparative advantages

The main driving force of the fly-geese story and continuous reallocation of production activities across Asian economies is the variation of wages in this area. Cheap labor has played an important role in attracting the labor-intensive production process of the technology-intensive products to China and has contributed to the increase in China’s trade surplus with US. However, China’s wage i s now increasing, which will result in a loss of comparative advantages in the labor-intensive production activities. According to Li, Li, Wu, & Xiong (2012), real annual wages of Chinese urban workers in 1978 was 1004 US dollars, while this value has increased to 5487 US dollars in 2010. The fast wage growth started around 1998, with an annual growth rate at 13.8% during 1998–2010 (Li et al., 2012). In 2015, China’s average annual manufacturing wage was about 9165 measured in 2010 USD. It’s more than double of the wage rate in Thailand, and more than triple of the wage in all other economies shown in Fig. Although China’s labor productivity is estimated to grow at an annual rate of 11.3% during 1997–2010 (Li et al., 2012), China’s labor is still more expjavascript:void(0)ensive than these economies. It implies that the labor markets regulations are experiencing dramatic changes, which might also impact the locations choice of multinational firms.

There are many factors that may explain China’s rising wage, s uch

as the rapid growth and accumulation of capita, the labor market reforms, privatization of state-owned enterprises, spillover from multinational firms, shortage of unskilled labor, and the economic structural change. As a consequence of the dramatic in crease of China’s manufacturing wage, the production process, which was transplanted to China during the 1990s from NIEs has being reallocated to other economies with wages much lower than China, such as Vietnam, Cambodia, Bangladesh, India, Indonesia and even as far as Africa (Lin, 2012, Lin, 2013). Their average wage was still below 2000 USD in 2016. the FDI inflows to China dropped from 243.70 billion (measured in 2010 USD) in 2010 to 154.91 billion USD in 2016, while the outward FDI from China expanded from 57.95 billion to 197.28 billion. Meanwhile, the FDI inflows to Vietnam increased from 0.8 billion to 11.44 billion.

There are two messages we can conclude from the discussion in this section. First, the pattern of China–US trade imbalances was mainly driven by the trade in sectors in which China has comparative advantages, mainly labor-intensive consumption-related manufacturing goods. Therefore, imposing border tariffs on imports from China will hurt US consumers. They will have to pay higher prices for goods either produced domestically or imported from other less competitive, labor-abundant countries. Second, even without imposing an extraordinary import tariff, there will be a reduction in China’s exports to the US due to the

reallocation of manufacturing production activities to other low-wage economies as a result of the increasing wages in China.

6. Conclusion

In this paper, we provide empirical evidences to show: (1) the East Asian economies are traditionally the major source of US’s trade defici ts and provider of labor-intensive manufacturing, consumer goods to the US due to the differences in comparative advantages between US and East Asian economies; (2) The relocation of labor-intensive manufacturing from other East Asian economies to China in a flying-geese pattern due to changing comparative advantages and the global production sharing contribute to the meteoric rise of China–US trade imbalances in the last three decades; (3) Even though the weight of China’s contribution to US’s trade deficit increased sharply after the 1990s, the contribution of East Asian economies as a group to US trade deficit in fact declined in the same period. Therefore, China and East Asian economies cannot be the main cause for the worsening of US trade imbalances after the 1970s; and (4) the China–US trade imbalance is expected to shrink with the rising of wage in China and the relocation of labor-intensive manufacturing from China to other low-wage labor abundant economies.

From the above facts and analysis, Preside nt Trump’s pledge of China as the reason for US’s trade deficit is incorrect and his proposal to impose draconian tariffs on China’s imports to the US will make little

contribution to reducing US’s overall trade imbalances and increasing US jobs. Such a measure may fasten the relocation of some manufacturing activities from China to other low-income economies and mitigate the US–China trade imbalance but not US’s total trade deficit. The US consumers will suffer if President Trump’s proposed tariff measure was implemented because they will have to pay higher prices for the imported manufacturing goods from either China or other economies.

中文

特朗普经济学与中美贸易失衡

贾斯汀·伊夫林

1.引言

美国的贸易逆差从70年代中期之前的最低值扩大到2006年的峰值,达到7,610亿美元,约占美国GDP的5%。商品贸易逆差甚至更大,在2006年达到峰值8,370亿美元。尽管该值在2008年全球金融危机之后有所下降,但在2016年仍高达7,520亿美元的显着水平。美国与其他国家之间的贸易失衡工业化经济体是80年代之前美国贸易逆差上升的最大原因,而近年来,美国主要对新兴的亚洲经济体和石油生产经济体产生逆差。特朗普总统辩称,美国的贸易逆差是由不利于美国的贸易协定引起的,并承诺通过双边谈判或单方面行动消除这些贸易协定。

自2015年总统大选以来,中美贸易失衡一直是特朗普的主要关

心问题。美国人口普查局提供的官方数据显示,作为全球化进程中新兴的主要参与者,中国一直在进行贸易自1984年以来对美国的贸易顺差。中国对美国的贸易顺差从1985年的0.6亿美元贸易顺差增加到2016年的3470.2亿美元贸易顺差,占当年美国贸易逆差的44%。这种巨大的失衡给中美贸易关系带来了巨大压力。一个主要问题是从中国进口的产品对美国国内就业的影响。Autor,Dorn和Hanson (2013)的一篇被高度引用的著作表明,从中国进口的产品对美国的制造业就业产生了负面影响。特朗普总统在竞选中保证对从中国进口的商品征收45%的边境税,以减少美中贸易失衡并保留美国的就业机会。

对从中国进口的商品征收严厉的关税,是否有助于减少美国的总贸易逆差?美国对华贸易逆差的减少会把制造业工作带回美国吗?这些问题的答案取决于导致持续性贸易失衡的原因。

美国贸易赤字上升的原因已被广泛讨论。现有文献为几个关键因素提供了理论和经验支持,例如新兴经济体缺乏投资机会,相对于几个新兴经济体货币的美元汇率被低估,主要商品价格上涨以及-金融管制放松造成的消费,并得到美元作为全球主要储备货币的支持。

本文重点关注中美之间的贸易不平衡,并研究中国在劳动密集型制造业活动中的比较优势,以及以中国为集散地的各经济体之间的全球生产共享,是双边贸易增长的主要来源中美之间的贸易失衡。特别是,本文首先分析了美国与其主要贸易伙伴之间的双边贸易方式,发现东亚传统上是美国贸易逆差的主要来源。该研究进一步发现,在中

P2P 金融下的中小企业融资互联网金融外文文献翻译最新译文

文献出处: Waitz M. The small and medium-sized enterprise financing under P2P finance [J]. Journal of Business Research, 2016, 8(6): 81-91. 原文 The small and medium-sized enterprise financing under P2P finance Waitz M Abstract Small and medium-sized enterprise financing difficult is worldwide difficult problem. Article introduces the concept of the Internet financial, mainly summarized the P2P financial in the development of financial innovation and integration of science and technology, a combination of academic research on P2P financial now of the five directions of various views and opinions. Points out the current P2P financial problems in the development of risk control, and analyses the trend of the Internet financial. Keywords: P2P financial; Financial innovation; Risk control 1 Introduction Look from the history of enterprise development, a large enterprise originate from small and medium-sized enterprises. Small and medium-sized enterprises (smes) is the most dynamic part of the national economy, often walk in the forefront of technology development, in the high-tech industry, clean energy, green economy, etc, have good performance, play an important role in the economic transformation. Small and medium-sized enterprise financing difficult is worldwide difficult problem. These small and medium-sized enterprise financing environment and narrow channels, more than 60% are unable to get a bank loan. At present, science and technology enterprises and the characteristics of light assets, financing difficulties, become a huge bottleneck of sustainable development. 2 The concept of the Internet financial In the past two years, the Internet financial show explosive growth, since 2014, the Internet financial sector performance strength. Current economic field exists the phenomenon of two special contradiction, one is the small and medium-sized

网评文章中美贸易战的一些认识和感悟

关于中美贸易战的一些认识与感悟7月6日,中美贸易战将实质性地打响第一枪,美国企图以“美国优先”理念重整世界秩序,以贸易战为手段打断中华民族伟大复兴之路。面对挑衅,我们进行了强有力的还击,“打得一拳开,免得百拳来”,贸易战没有输赢,但我们一定是赢家。贸易战本身没有赢家,但是贸易战会有溢出效应,这个外溢效应在于政治收益。 首先贸易保护主义是逆势而动不得人心。贸易战是美国的霸权行径,几乎所有国家都强烈反对,其中包括美国重要盟友们。不得人心,中国有打赢贸易战的国际道义基础。这次中国不但是为自己而战,也是为全世界公平正义而战。美国,奉行“美国优先”事事与邻为壑,和全世界打贸易战。在自身无法带领世界推动经济发展的情况下,为保持自己优势竟试图用贸易战等手段迫他国割肉奉美,不合道义。与美不同,中国坚持“共商、共建、共享”,对邻居坚持亲邻、友邻、善邻,愿意与全世界共同建设“人类命运共同体”。孰高孰低、谁更受欢迎一目了然。正所谓人心所向,中国反击能赢得世界认可,贸易战开局中国已赢道义之战,这就是政治收益。 其次,贸易战能让中国奠定作为第二大经济体的强国地位。想想看,美国,不可一世的霸权国家,到处横行霸道,耀武扬威。美国对我们发起贸易战,我们没有退缩,我们众志成城,顶住压力,和美国叫板。随着时间推移大家发现原来美国不但不能把中国怎么样,中国实力还在不断增强,那意味着白宫用贸易战为中国经济实力做了背书,中国经济强国的地位反而因此彰显。那么世界会看到中国的实力,这个忍辱负重韬光养晦的国家,现在已经不是昔日吴下阿蒙,这会让世界对中国刮目相看。 再次,贸易战能让中国人民更加团结。贸易战是美国妄图打断中华民族伟大复

会计经济金融外文翻译外文文献英文文献发达国家和发展中国家的ERP实施问题

ERP implementation issues in advanced and developing countries Abstract There is an increasing need to implement a total business solution which supports major functionalities of a business. Enterprise resource planning (ERP) software is designed to meet this need, and has been widely adopted by organizations in developed countries. Meanwhile, ERP is beginning to appear in many organizations of developing countries. Little research has been conducted to compare the implementation practices of ERP in developed vs developing countries. Our research shows that ERP technology faces additional challenges in developing countries related to economic, cultural, and basic infrastructure issues. This article identifies a range of issues concerning ERP implementation by making a comparison of advanced and developing countries. Key words: Enterprise Resource management; Implementation; Developing countries. Enterprise resource planning (ERP) is an industry term for the broad set of activities supported by multi-module application software that helps a manufacturer or a service business manage the important parts of its business. Evolving from MRP systems, ERP has played a significant role in IT for several decades. Since the first symbiotic ERP product SAP created in 1972, ERP market revenues are expected to be as high as $52 billion by the year 2002. While there is wide acceptance of ERP in developed countries such as the USA, Canada, the UK, and Australia, developing countries lag far behind. At present, North America occupies 66 percent of the ERP market, Europe takes 22 percent, while the whole of Asia is only at 9 percent. However, due to economic growth, developing countries in Asia and Latin America are becoming major targets of big ERP vendors. ERP in developed countries ERP systems have been widely used by companies in developed countries. Organizations in manufacturing, service, and energy industries adopt ERP to:

互联网金融外文翻译银行业是必要的而银行不是,互联网时代的金融中介的未来

译文 银行业是必要的而银行不是,互联网时代的金融中介机构的未来 摘要 本文探讨了互联网时代下金融机构和银行作为特殊的金融机构的未来可能是怎样的问题。由于互联网而导致的交易费用的减少会降低进入金融产品市场的壁垒,因为有可能不再需要运行成本密集型的分支的大型系统。但是,对金融机构的职能研究表明,不是每个人都可以销售和经销金融产品。这是真的,因为金融业务中的信息不对称问题需要一个拥有良好信誉的中介,也因为需要限制大型资本基金转换资产的风险。这两个要求变现了进入金融中介市场的重要壁垒。并不是每一个金融产品会因为互联网的崛起而将面临更多的竞争,只有那些标准化和低风险的产品。此外,那些拥有可观资本和良好声誉的大公司可能被视为银行的新竞争者。 关键字:银行业,银行,金融机构,互联网 1、引言 “银行业是19世纪的钢铁行业。”当谈到关于新的信息技术对银行的影响的谈论时,这句话经常被提起。更一般来说,可能有人会问,新信息技术是如何成功的,特别是互联网的,可能会改变商业和金融机构的市场情况。在互联网的帮助下,人们可以执行所有银行的业务,而不需要银行。这意味着传统银行分支机构的中介。此外,互联网已经使客户直接从网上购买股票而不需要访问当地的分支银行。从更广泛的意义上来说,在互联网的帮助下,金融市场的供给和需求可能通过互联网满足,而不需要金融中介机构。互联网的崛起是否真的是金融中介机构的威胁?在急剧减少的交易成本情况下,商业和竞争将如何变化?本文考察了互联网的成功对金融机构和银行的影响。 2、金融机构的发展 几个世纪以来,许多金融交易需要个人的存在。随着现代信息技术的发展,这些都被改变了。如今,客户可以在不进入当地分支银行的情况下进行任何金融交易。转移支付和支付账单可以通过网络进行,个人金融交易以及关于金融问题的信息咨询业可以通过网络进行。此外,互联网创新类似智能卡或者其他电子支付系统消除了为了得到一些现金而访问分支银行的需要。 但是互联网也会改变咨询活动:在许多情况下,它甚至可能减少个人存在的

财务管理外文文献翻译

附件1:外文资料翻译译文 财务报表分析 A.财务比率 我们需要使用财务比率来分析财务报表,比较财务报表的分析方法不能真正有效的得出想要的结果,除非采取的是研究在报表中项目与项目之间关系的形式。例如,只是知道史密斯公司在一个特定的日期中拥有10000美元的现金余额,对我们是没有多大价值的。但是,假如我们知道,这种余额在这种平衡中有4%的流动负债,而一年前的现金余额有25%的流动负债。由于银行家对公司通常要求现金余额保持在银行信用度的20%,不管使用或不使用,如果公司的财务状况出现问题,我们可以立即发现。 我们可以对比比较财务报表中的项目,作出如下结论: 1. 项目之间的资产负债表比较: a)在资产负债表中的一个日期之间的比较,例如项目,现金与流动负债相比; b)同一项目在资产负债表中一个日期与另一个日期之间的比较,例如,现在的现金与一年前比较; c)比较两个项目之间在资产负债表中一个日期和一个相似比率在资产负债表中的另一个日期的比率,例如,现在现金流动负债的比率与另一个项目一年前的相似比率和已经标记的现金状况趋势的比较。 2.项目报表中收入和支出的比较: a)一定时期中的报表项目的比较; b)同一项目在报表中现阶段与上个阶段的比较; c)报表中项目之间的比率与去年相似比率的比较; 3.资产负债表中的项目与报表中收入和支出项目的比较: a)在这些报表项目之间的一个给定的时间内,例如,今年净利润可能以百分比计算今年净值; b)两个报表中项目之间的比率在这几年时间的比较,例如,净利润的比率占今年净值的百分比与去年或者前年的相似比率的比较 如果我们采用上述比较或比率,然后依次比较它们,我们的比较分析结果将获得重要意义:

互联网金融发展文献综述及外文文献资料P2P金融

本份文档包含:关于该选题的外文文献、文献综述 一、外文文献 标题: Online brokers lead the way for French internet finance 作者: Caffard, Christophe 期刊名称: International Financial Law Review 卷: 20;期: 3;页: 20-24 Online brokers lead the way for French internet finance 1 Regulated brokers Regulated brokers are legal entities which have an investment services licence and are subject to the prudential regulations of the Comite de Reglementation Bancaire et Financiere (CRBF) and the Conseil des Marches Financiers (CMF). * Choice of legal form: regulated brokers are not required to be incorporated in a specific legal form; however, under article 13 of the MAF Law, the CECEI checks whether the legal form of the brokerage company is appropriate for providing investment services. In practice, any type of commercial company is admitted: societes de capitaux (limited companies) or societes de personnes (partnerships). The formalities of share transfer, tax and the scope of liability of a company's management will be relevant factors to the choice of legal form. * Application for an investment services licence from the CECEI: the most important part of the application is the description of the investment services, and a business plan including prospective financial statements for the following three years. The CMF will check whether the business plan is consistent with the investment services licence requested by the broker. The CECEI will ensure that the applicant's own initial funds are consistent with the business plan. The scope of the investment services licence is variable and covers one or more ofthe following investment services: Reception and transmission of orders to another investment services provider on behalf of investors, for execution. This is the core investment service provided by the

互联网金融对传统金融业的影响外文文献翻译

互联网金融对传统金融业的影响外文文献翻译(文档含中英文对照即英文原文和中文翻译) 译文: 互联网金融对传统金融业的影响 摘要 网络的发展,深刻地改变甚至颠覆了许多传统行业,金融业也不例外。近年来,金融业成为继商业分销、传媒之后受互联网影响最为深远的领域,许多基于互联网的金融服务模式应运而生,并对传统金融业产生了深刻的影响和巨大的冲击。“互联网金融”成为社会各界关注的焦点。 互联网金融低成本、高效率、关注用户体验,这些特点使其能够充分满足传统金融“长尾市场”的特殊需求,灵活提供更为便捷、高

效的金融服务和多样化的金融产品,大大拓展了金融服务的广度和深度,缩短了人们在时空上的距离,建立了一种全新的金融生态环境;可以有效整合、利用零散的时间、信息、资金等碎片资源,积少成多,形成规模效益,成为各类金融服务机构新的利润增长点。此外,随着互联网金融的不断渗透和融合,将给传统金融行业带来新的挑战和机遇。互联网金融可以促进传统银行业的转型,弥补传统银行在资金处理效率、信息整合等方面的不足;为证券、保险、基金、理财产品的销售与推广提供新渠道。对于很多中小企业来说,互联网金融拓展了它们的融资渠道,大大降低了融资门槛,提高了资金的使用效率。但是,互联网金融的跨行业性决定了它的风险因素更为复杂、敏感、多变,因此要处理好创新发展与市场监管、行业自律的关系。 关键词:互联网金融;商业银行;影响;监管 1 引言 互联网技术的不断发展,云计算、大数据、社交网络等越来越多的互联网应用为传统行业的业务发展提供了有力支持,互联网对传统行业的渗透程度不断加深。20世纪末,微软总裁比尔盖茨就曾断言,“传统商业银行会成为新世纪的恐龙”。如今,随着互联网电子信息技术的发展,我们真切地感受到了这种趋势,移动支付、电子银行早已在我们的日常生活中占据了重要地位。 由于互联网金融的概念几乎完全来自于商业实践,因此目前的研究多集中在探讨互联网金融的具体模式上,而对传统金融行业的影响力分析和应对措施则缺乏系统性研究。互联网与金融行业一向是风险

金融学专业外文翻译(中英对照、翻译专业修改好了的)

论文题目:关于巴塞尔II:新巴塞尔资本协议的影响 学院名称:财经学院专业班级:金融0814班学生姓名:王庆贺 外文题目:Dealing with Basel II: the impact of the New Basel Capital Accord 出处:Balance Sheet,2003,Vol.11(No.4) 作者:Thomas Garside and Jens Bech 译文: 关于巴塞尔II:新巴塞尔资本协议的影响 托马斯·加赛德和杰尼斯·伯克 摘要:国际监管机构在2003年完成新资本协议,银行决定在2006年底执行这个协议。巴塞尔协议是对全球银行业改革的监管。在本文中,我们回顾新巴塞尔资本协议内容以及一些我们所期望对欧洲银行业发生的重要影响。正如在第一届巴塞尔协议修正案(Basel I)中,我们得出结论,新巴塞尔协议不仅对持有资本额的数量做了规定,还对银行业的战略格局进行展望。 关键词:银行,流动性,监管,风险管理 新巴塞尔资本协议的新规则 巴塞尔委员会虽然只是公布了三分之一,但这很可能是协商的最后新资本协议(Basel II)文件。这项建议如获通过,将会深刻地改变银行的偿付能力的方式,监管机构监管银行风险管理实施过程和银行必须对市场参与者公布的风险信息量,经过讨论会,巴塞尔委员会预计将在2003年底发布的新资本协议的最后草案。 目前的巴塞尔资本协议(Basel I)对达到加强国际金融体系的稳定的既定目标已经有了显著成效,通过在不同国家持续应用本协议的同时,增加了资本水平,创造了一个更公平的竞争领域。总的来说,目前的全球一级资本的平均水平从1993年的约6%升至8%,此外,巴塞尔资本协议已经应用于100多个国家,远远超过最初的预期。 尽管实现其最初目标的成效很明显,很显然,对于巴塞尔我有一些意想不到的不

对中美贸易摩擦的看法

对中美贸易摩擦/贸易战的看法 一、美国贸易战回顾 当今世界,中、欧、美、日、俄形成了世界上5大力量中心。而美国在历史上与其他4个国家和地区发生过贸易冲突。 1.1 二战后美国与日本的贸易战回顾与分析 20世纪70年代石油危机后,日本的小型省油轿车迅速占领美国市场。1979年,日本汽车在美国市场的占有率为17%,1980年快速上升到24%,并取代美国成为世界上最大的汽车生产国。与此相反,美国的大汽车公司经营业绩直线下降。于是美国针对日本经济严重依赖出口、投资及产业结构严重失衡的问题,决定通过贸易战来抑制日本出口,进而降低其经济竞争。这使日本与美国等国家在1985年签署《广场协议》,随后美国对日本展开贸易、金融、汇率等多维打击,日本的贸易顺差与出口增速均有所回落。之后,日本虽通过国际并购与境外投资刺激了经济,且国际资本受日元持续强劲升值预期的吸引进入日本的股市与房地产,但日本企业的跨国投资与国内的股市、房市很快呈现泡沫化,且日趋严重。而同期日本政府并没有意识到境外投资、国内房地产与金融市场泡沫化的重大风险,以致在泡沫自然破裂后,日本房市与股市自20 世纪90 年代初开始持续下行,日本经济遂陷入长期低迷,迎来了“失去的20 年”。 1.2 二战后美国与欧共体(欧盟)的贸易战回顾与分析 欧共体成立后,规定了统一的农产品价格,建立了共同的农产品进口关税,取消了成员国之间的关税,建立了共同农业基金,同时,还主动调节农产品市场,对

出口进行补贴并进行技术革新等。这一系列的农业政策,提升了西欧各国农业生产的稳定性,也使农业生产者的积极性及农产品产量获得大幅度提升,西欧各国也逐渐从农业净进口国转变为净出口国。这显然对美国的农业市场构成了威胁。于是美国开始针对欧共体内部的调节手段进行批评,认为欧共体在农产品领域的高额关税行为属于“贸易保护”,并不符合“自由贸易”精神,但并未能阻挡欧共体继续提升美国农产品的进口关税税率。随着欧共体农产品出口量的快速增长,并影响到美国的出口市场,美国对欧共体的指责也从征收高额关税等“贸易保护行为”转为出口补贴等“不公平贸易手段”上。 在钢铁领域,美国钢铁公司、伯利恒钢铁公司等七家钢铁企业以联邦德国等西欧十一国钢铁公司接受政府补贴,并以低于成本以下的价格向美国倾销钢材为由,在1982 年1 月中上旬,向美国商务部和国际贸易委员会提交了针对西欧十一国钢铁公司的“反倾销”与“反补贴”的诉讼。之后美欧在钢铁领域的贸易战显着升级。2001 年 6 月,全球钢铁行业面临产能过剩问题,美国国内钢铁厂商经营困难。于是,在行业协会要求下,美国针对欧盟、日本、韩国等国家和地区的钢铁产品出口可能给美国钢铁产业造成严重损害,从而涉嫌违反“201 条款”进行了全球保障措施调查。最终的调查结果确认上述国家钢铁出口违反了“201 条款”。在美国国际贸易委员会(USITC)提交报告后,布什总统裁定,自2002 年3月20 日开始,对大多数种类钢材进口征收为期3 年,最高达30% 的关税,并对厚钢板实行进口限额,同时实行钢材进口许可制度。受此影响,欧盟、日韩等国家和地区的钢材出口量大减。 1.3 二战后美国与苏联/俄罗斯的贸易战回顾与分析 二战后,美苏由同盟转为争霸,美苏贸易在此期间充当了美苏关系的“指示器”。

互联网金融外文翻译文献

文献信息: 文献标题:INTERNET FINANCE: DIGITAL CURRENCIES AND ALTERNATIVE FINANCE LIBERATING THE CAPITAL MARKETS(互联网金融:数字货币和替代金融解放资本市场) 国外作者:Kim Wales 文献出处:《Journal of Governance and Regulation》, 2015,4(1):190-201 字数统计:英文2505单词,13427字符;中文4405汉字 外文文献: INTERNET FINANCE: DIGITAL CURRENCIES AND ALTERNATIVE FINANCE LIBERATING THE CAPITAL MARKETS Abstract This article discusses how the sudden shift in policy reform and innovation has the potential to liberate the financial markets. The economic potential of internet finance is beginning to take hold across the capital markets as industries like Peer–to–Peer Lending, Equity and Debt based Crowdfunding and virtual currencies and cryptocurrencies which are types of digital currency are quickly transforming the way businesses are being financed. From borrowing and lending, buying and selling securities, to conducting wire transfers internationally, these innovations are creating a new class and generation of investors will source investments opportunities. Helping institutions and governments assess risks and manage performance in order to determine where to deploy capital; and showing signs of lessening the inequality gap. Following the neolithic agricultural revolution and the industrial revolution, this new revolution will enable more people to access financial services in less traditional ways, especially the unbanked world with its huge potential. These new financial opportunities, such as peer –to - peer (P2P) lending, will be discussed and examined, and we will stress how they can allow people to bypass

网络经济与金融的应用【外文翻译】

本科毕业论文(设计) 外文翻译 原文: Network Economics with Application to Finance Networks and network externalities play a central role in the New Industrial Organization. Many network industries, such as telecommunications, railroads etc., are central to modern economic life. Further, the essential relationships among the components of the network, i.e., complimentarily and compatibility, are present in many non-network industries, including financial intermediation and the exchange of financial instruments and assets. In this paper, we analyze and review the essential features of networks and show their application to finance. A crucial feature of networks is that they exhibit network externalities, i.e., production or consumption positive size externalities. In a typical network, the addition of a new customer (or network node) increases the willingness to pay for network services by all participants. When a new node is added to a network, new goods are created. Consumers demand these goods that were unavailable before. Thus, consumers are better off after the new node was added. The benefits of the addition of an extra node (or an extra customer) exceed the private benefits accruing to the particular node (or customer). As an example of this, consider a simple star network consisting of a central node S and peripheral nodes A, B, C, etc., as in Figure 1. This can be a telecommunications network if S is a central switch and A, B, C, etc. are the locations of the various customers. Customers demand phone calls ASB, BSA, ASC, etc. These are composite goods, each comprised of two complementary components; for example ASB is comprised of AS and SB. Networks are by their nature self-reinforcing. This is just another way of saying that they exhibit positive size externalities. As a direct consequence of their self-reinforcing nature, networks frequently exhibit positive critical mass. This means

中美贸易摩擦的分析

中美贸易摩擦地分析 一、中美贸易摩擦现状分析 中国和美国是世界上最大地发展中国家和最大地发达国家,两国之间地贸易关系自年两国建交以来获得了迅速而全面地发展,这对中美双方和世界经济都是一件大事、好事.自年起,伴随着中国加入世界贸易组织,中美经贸关系更是进入加速增长地新阶段,接连跃升新台阶.至年底,年中两国贸易年均增长率达到%,堪称世界之最.中美贸易额年突破亿美元大关,达到亿美元,年突破亿美元大关,达到亿美元,年更达亿美元.目前,美国是中国地最大贸易伙伴国和最大地海外市场.年中美贸易额占中国外贸总额地%,对美出口额占中国出口总额地%.在中美贸易额飞速增长地同时美中贸易逆差不断加大,按美方计算,从年起,美国对华贸易年年逆差,年为亿美元,到年增为亿美元,增加了多倍,年美国对华逆差占美国外贸逆差总额地三分之一以上.b5E2R。 二、中美贸易摩擦地原因分析 在世界经济发展不均衡地背景下,全球贸易保护主义重新抬头,中美两国作为全球两大经济体,不可避免地会出现贸易摩擦,这些给中美贸易关系增添了诸多不确定性.p1E a n。 (一)美方原因造成地两国贸易摩擦 .经济低迷与新贸易保护主义重新抬头 近年来,美国经济地低迷与中国地“和平崛起”形成强烈反差.根据美国商务部地初步统计数据显示,年首季,美国经济仅增长,增速低于分析人士原来预计地和去年第四季度地,是过去四年来地最小增幅,而住房投资下降仍是导致经济减速地主要原因.历史经验表明,贸易保护强弱与经济发展状况有一定地联系,因此只要经济衰退或美国国内产业竞争力下降,美国地贸易保护主义就会重新抬头,并且会采取限制进口,鼓励出口地新贸易保护主义地相关手段,中美贸易发生摩擦不可避免.D X D i T。 .美国国内政治因素地影响 美国总统大选每四年举行一次,自冷战结束以来地历次美国总统大选中,美国对华政策都是两党总统候选人相互攻击地重要议题,这也是

互联网金融安全中英文对照外文翻译文献

互联网金融安全中英文对照外文翻译文献 中英文对照外文翻译文献(文档含英文原文和中文翻译)

Database Security in a Web Environment Introduction Databases have been common in government departments and commercial enterprises for many years. Today, databases in any organization are increasingly opened up to a multiplicity of suppliers, customers, partners and employees - an idea that would have been unheard of a few years ago. Numerous applications and their associated data are now accessed by a variety of users requiring different levels of access via manifold devices and channels – often simultaneously. For example: ? Online banks allow customers to perform a variety of banking operations - via the Internet and over the telephone – whilst maintaining the privacy of account data. ? E-Commerce merchants and their Service Providers must store customer, order and payment data on their merchant server - and keep it secure. ? HR departments allow employees to update their personal information –whilst protecting certain management information from unauthorized access. ? The medical profession must protect the confidentiality of patient data –whilst allowing essential access for treatment. ? Online brokerages need to be able to provide large numbers of simultaneous users with up-to-date and accurate financial information. This complex landscape leads to many new demands upon system security. The global growth of complex web-based infrastructures is driving a need for security solutions that provide mechanisms to segregate environments; perform integrity checking and maintenance; enable strong authentication and non-repudiation; and provide for confidentiality. In turn, this necessitates comprehensive business and technical risk assessment to identify the threats,

互联网金融外文文献翻译 2

外文出处:DeBonisR, Silvestrini A. Internet finance and its influence ontraditional banking [J]. Applied FinancialEconomics, 2016,3(5):409-425. 原文 Internetfinanceanditsinfluenceontraditionalbanking De BonisR, SilvestriniA A b stracts With the rapid development of information technology, Internet financialmodel graduallyrise.ThispapersummarizestheInternetfinancialmodelonthebasisofth e concept, features and functions of Internet financial model in strategy,customer channels,financing, pricingand financial disintermediation of the impact of the tra di ti o nal c om mercial bank. T his paper a r g ue s t hat Inte rne t financ i al m ode l in the short term will not stand in the way of commercial bank's traditional business modelandprofit,butinthelongtermcommercialBanksshoulduseoftheInternetfinancial model, in order to obtain the new development. At the same time, the sustainedandhealthy development of the Internet industry to rely on Internet financialenterprises e lf-di s c i pli ne,posit i ve i nnovat i on,but a lsoattrac t m orec us t ome rs,strengt he nt h e construction ofsystemsecurity. Key words: Financial innovation; Internet financial; Financialdisintermediation At p r e s ent, m obi le payment, online ba nking, m obil e ba nki ng and financ i al businessinChina'sbooming financialinnovationssuchascloud,thusformedanew kind of financial model -- the Internet finance. Big data era and brand creation,spread tothedevelopmentoffinancialinstitutionsisbothachallengeandopportunity.Alo ng with the development of the Internet financial, emerging Internet traditionalfinancialcompanies and financial institutions will be a fierce competition, the future mayeven change thetraditional financial management mode and operationpattern. The Inter net financial concepts, features andfunctions The concept of the Inter net financial. After years of development, Internet companies stay in business does not provide

相关文档
相关文档 最新文档